.
“If the only tool you have is a hammer, every problem looks like a
nail”! Abraham Maslow.
That may well sum up the current predicament
of Bernanke and many of his counterparts in Europe with interest rates at
record low for about four years now.
After launching Quantitative Easing 1 (known as QE1) of US$1.65trillion and QE2 of US$600bn, to stave off deflation, Fed has now launched QE Infinity to boost
employment. It has committed to buy $40bn of agency mortgage-backed securities every month
until the labour market improves. An open ended commitment (as he has not been
specific on unemployment targets) besides promising to hold the ultra-low rates
until mid-2015.
It signals that he is prepared to hold an accommodative policy
stance even if economy gains strength and has moved away from the deflation
argument. But before
we get to analyse the merits and effectiveness of QE Infinity, let’s understand the theory
of behind benefits of QE and why some economists seem to worship it.
How does QE work?
QE is an unconventional emergency tool of
monetary policy that the Central Banks can use to boost the economy by pumping
liquidity into the system. The Central Bank generates fresh amounts of
electronic money to encourage lending to businesses. Specifically, the Bank
buys assets like Government and corporate bonds with its new cash. The
companies selling those assets - usually commercial banks or other financial
businesses such as insurance companies - will then have new money in their
accounts, which in turn should feed into the wider economy.
Central banks create money to buy
government, and sometimes corporate, bonds, for three main reasons:
- To reduce the cost of borrowing - buying government bonds increases their price and lowers their yield, which in turn puts downward pressure on interest rates across the spectrum;
- To inflate asset prices - with bonds paying out lower interest rates, investors look to buy other asset classes, such as equities, real estate thereby pushing prices up;
- To increase lending - by paying money to banks to buy bonds, the banks then have more money to lend to businesses and individuals.
In theory if QE works, credit growth
should pick up and businesses should find it easier to get credit.
How is this different from actions of the 1920s
Germany and Mugabe’s Zimbabwe?
Weimar Republic (German Reich)
resorted to printing money to finance government debt and war reparation
damages. The value of the Papiermark declined from 4.2 per U.S. dollar at the
outbreak of World War I to 1 million per dollar by August 1923 and a further
slid to 238 million to dollar by November 1923. Following this, new terms were
negotiated, a new currency was introduced, at a rate of 1 trillion Papiermark
for one Rentenmark, bringing back the US Dollar to 4.2 to a Rentenmark!
More recent actions of printing money were undertaken in
Mugabe’s Zimbabwe. In 1980, Zim dollar was worth US$ 1.54. In March 2007, the
Z$ 500,000-note was issued, signalling the official arrival of hyperinflation
(more than 50% inflation per month). In January,
2009, Zimbabwe issued the one-hundred-trillion Zim dollar note, the largest denomination banknote ever!!
It marked the end of the currency. In February 2009, the Reserve Bank of
Zimbabwe introduced the fourth Zim dollar, which chopped off 12 zeros. Finally
in 2009 the currency was abandoned, a humiliating end.
In contrast the US and the UK are
buying asset backed securities and government bonds. To the extent banks are required to hold
government bonds as regulatory liquidity requirements, Central Banks buying of
bonds indirectly feeds the government deficit financing, very similar to
printing money!
Has it ever worked ?
No. Let's look at Japan’s lost decade(s) - After keeping rates near zero for an extended period, the
Bank of Japan finally launched QE in March 2001 and dropped in March
2006. Over the five years, the Bank of Japan increased its outright
purchases of longer-dated Japanese government securities driving the call-money
rates to zero. The policy helped to stabilise the weak banks but failed to spur
growth.
At first, it appeared the program had succeeded in
stabilizing the economy and halting the slide in prices. But deflation returned
with a vengeance, putting the Bank of Japan back on the spot. Critics say the
Japanese central bank wasn't aggressive enough in launching and expanding its
bond-buying program—then dropped it too soon. Others
say Japan simply waited too long to resort to the policy.
BOJ officials have said quantitative easing wasn't the right
tool to fight Japan's deflation, which was rooted in structural problems such
as a rigid employment system that failed to eliminate redundant jobs to stay
competitive.
Some economists support QE as the
right medicine, then why doesn’t it work?
The arguments for QE are based on money multiplier effect. As
the available reserves increases, banks ability to lend increases, creating the
money multiplier effect leading to economic recovery. But for this to work economic conditions
needs to be different!
Factors that are NOT aiding monetary transmission or lending
growth:
- Banks are over leveraged and capital deficient; additional cheap source of liquidity is helping it to refinance expensive funding and improve profitability; but very little flow through to the real economy;
- Interest rates have remained low for 4 years and yet demand has been muted, further QE is not going to spur demand;
- Over leveraged consumer, weak labour market combined with declining home prices have failed to create any new housing demand;
- Small business are not looking to borrow due to the uncertain economic outlook;
- Large corporations will borrow more at even lower rates — even though they’re already sitting on mountains of cash.
But such large
corporation borrowing won’t create new jobs and may even lead to job losses as they
invest their cheaper cash to achieve further economies through mergers and
acquisitions. QE1 reduced
corporate-borrowing rates by nearly a percentage point; while QE2 succeeded in
bringing down corporate rates by only 13 basis points. The law of diminishing
returns come into play.
Banks have increased their reserves with the Central Bank rather than
use the proceeds of QE for further lending. The average level of excess reserves for
banks was roughly $19 billion from 1984 to 2008.
Since 2008 excess
reserves held at banks has swelled to more than $1.5 trillion currently!! As
explained earlier, this is due to the combination of lack of demand for credit
and overstretched balance sheet of banks.
While the pending inventory has dropped to
pre-crisis levels of 6 months, this conceals the housing market weakness as the effects of foreclosure moratorium and pending foreclosures on home owners
(estimated at 700,000) is not reflected in this. The average time take to foreclose has also increased
from 4 months in to over 12 months.
Once banks
recommence their foreclosure process, the supply overhang will continue. This combined with lack of credit
growth will push the housing market recovery further out.
Quantitative easing didn’t help the
Japanese economy, instead it only big Japanese companies and the current
experience will be no different.
Do QE programmes have
any effect on employment…
The chart shows net gains in employment since beginning of 2009 as compared to the number
of individuals that have moved into the "Not In Labor Force" category where they are no
longer counted. While there was an increase of 3.4 million jobs since the financial crisis, that is far lower for a sustainable economic recovery. At the
same time, more that 8.4 million have either "given up" or "retired" during that period. The decline in
unemployment rate to 8.3% is partly as a result of a fall in workforce participation.
There is NO evidence that bond buying programs have
any effect on fostering employment. However, at the current rate of
individuals leaving the work force, Bernanke is likely to achieve low unemployment
rate in the next few of years! Of course, economic prosperity will
have deteriorated much further as the rise of the "welfare state" persists.
The charts below show the number of individuals, since 2009, who are now claiming disability and food stamps and the increase in welfare costs.
If core inflation is
benign, what is the harm in pursuing QE?
The Federal Reserve claims QE is not a problem because
"core inflation" has been relatively contained. But core inflation
excludes food and energy prices, which are two of the biggest components of
consumer budgets and have been rising. On top of that, the
average US household income has declined by over 9% since the onset of recession.
As a result, food and energy consume more of wages and salaries it leaves less
available for consumption within other areas of the economy. The chart below
shows the consumer conundrum where declining wages meet up with rising costs of
food and energy. With recent severe drought in the US food prices will only
rise further. Of course, the USD benefits from its status as a reserve currency that offsets potentially severe outcomes.
The important point is that for businesses to hire require an increase in aggregate end demand. Rising inflationary
pressures in food and energy prices only act as depressants to discretionary consumption thereby
reducing the need for employers to expand capacity. It is unlikely that
the Fed's purchases of mortgage back securities will spur businesses to expand. The inflation expectation has also risen above 2 per cent and there is little justification for additional QE at this point.
Conclusion
While QE will push liquidity into the equity
markets thereby inducing higher asset prices - it will do little to help the economy,
employment or housing. Money
will chase anything that is perceived as a “hard asset.” Industrial metals have already risen by 16.6 per cent since early August. The S&P is near all time highs, but if viewed in terms of gold it is 61 per cent below its 2007
high. Fed is engaged in debasing the dollar and this leading to competitive devaluation from other Central Banks (Japan has reacted).
Monetary policy has a very limited reach
economically and cannot be a substitute for fiscal policy measures that are required
to promote economic growth.
With the consumer sentiment weak, unemployment
high, foreclosures and delinquencies still burdensome, and businesses
constrained by lack of demand - there is little desire or need and even if
there was, the banks are too constrained to lend. This is unlikely to
change anytime soon even as businesses are forced to pullback as demand is
further reduced by rising inflationary pressures.
The lack of employment, lower incomes, excess debt
and poor credit history will keep a large chunk of the population from
qualifying to avail a mortgage for quite some time. If the lowest
mortgage rates in history could not lead a housing market recovery, there is
little likelihood that a few more basis points will do the trick.
With QE Infinity, Bernanke is determined to pump up the US economy,
full throttle. Be prepared for the next asset bubble burst, only this
time it’s going to be a lot bigger and a lot more painful!
No comments:
Post a Comment